Accumulation and
Reproduction of Capital
Marx begins this third part
of Capital, Volume 2 as follows:
“The direct
process of the production of capital is its labour and self-expansion process,
the process whose result is the commodity-product and whose compelling motive
is the production of surplus-value.”
Here Marx is confirming, in
direct terms, the order of things as explained in Capital, Volume 1. The motive
of capital is the production of surplus-value, and the commodity-product is the
consequence. Some would call this production for profit and not for need;
others might say that it is the creation and the reproduction of a power
relationship of the bourgeois owners over the working class.
Marx continues to assist. In
contrast to the end of the second section of Volume 2, where he left us with
more questions than answers, at the beginning of the third section he lays out
the scheme of Volume 1 (“ Book 1”) and all three sections of Volume 2 as
follows (shortened; see Chapter 18 for the full text):
“In Book I
the process of capitalist production was analysed as an individual act as well
as a process of reproduction: the production of surplus-value and the
production of capital itself. The only act within the sphere of circulation on
which we have dwelt was the purchase and sale of labour-power as the
fundamental condition of capitalist production.
“In the first
part of this Book II, the various forms were considered which capital assumes
its circular movement, and the various forms of this movement itself. The
circulation time must now be added to the working times discussed in Book I.
“In the
second Part, the circuit was studied as being periodic, i.e., as a turnover.
“…Especially
money-capital came forward with distinctive features not shown in Book I.
Certain laws were found according to which diverse large components of a given
capital must be continually advanced and renewed — depending on the conditions
of the turnover — in the form of money-capital in order to keep a productive
capital of a given size constantly functioning.
“But in both
the first and the second Parts it was always only a question of some individual
capital, of the movement of some individualised part of social capital.
“However the
circuits of the individual capitals intertwine, presuppose and necessitate one
another, and form, precisely in this interlacing, the movement of the total
social capital.
“We have now
to study the process of circulation (which in its entirety is a form of the
process of reproduction) of the individual capitals as components of the
aggregate social capital, that is to say, the process of circulation of this
aggregate social capital.”
There are four chapters in
the third part of Volume 2. Chapter 18 is covered above. Chapter 19 doubles
back to the Physiocrats and Adam Smith. Chapter 20 is very long, covering many
kinds of ordinary and extraordinary circumstances, divided into four parts; but
it begins with a useful schematic summary, as follows:
“The total
product, and therefore the total production, of society may be divided into two
major departments:
“I. Means of Production, commodities
having a form in which they must, or at least may, pass into productive
consumption.
“II. Articles of Consumption,
commodities having a form in which they pass into the individual consumption of
the capitalist and the working-class.
“All the
various branches of production pertaining to each of these two departments form
one single great branch of production, that of the means of production in the
one case, and that of articles of consumption in the other. The aggregate
capital employed in each of these two branches of production constitutes a
separate large department of the social capital.
“In each
department the capital consists of two parts:
“1) Variable Capital. This capital, so
far as its value is concerned, is equal to the value of the social labour-power
employed in this branch of production; in other words, it is equal to the sum
of the wages paid for this labour-power. So far as its substance is concerned,
it consists of the labour-power in action, i.e., of the living labour set in
motion by this capital-value.
“2) Constant Capital. This is the value
of all the means of production employed for productive purposes in this branch.
These, again, are divided into fixed capital, such as machines, instruments of
labour, buildings, labouring animals, etc., and circulating constant capital,
such as materials of production: raw and auxiliary materials, semi-finished
products, etc.
“The value of
the total annual product created with the aid of this capital in each of the
two departments consists of one portion which represents the constant capital c consumed in the process of production
and only transferred to the product in accordance with its value, and of
another portion added by the entire labour of the year. This latter portion is
divided in turn into the replacement of the advanced variable capital v and the excess over and above it,
which forms the surplus-value s. And
just as the value of every individual commodity, that of the entire annual
product of each department consists of c
+ v + s.”
Reading for Discussion
We shall use Part 1 of
Chapter 21, the last chapter in Volume 2, for a reading text, attached, and
downloadable via the link below.
It is called “Accumulation
and Reproduction on an Extended Scale”, thus confirming what Volume 2 is about,
namely these two words which feature very prominently in 21st
century South African communist literature: Reproduction and Accumulation. At
seven thousand words, Part 1 of Chapter 21 is sufficiently short and
sufficiently plain in its prose to be read as a discussion document.
Let it suffice, therefore,
for this introduction, to point out that in Volume 2, Marx is examining the leads
and lags in the full cycle of the accumulation and reproduction of capital, and
discovering features that arise during this circulation (e.g. “…money-capital came forward with
distinctive features not shown in Book I”) which have a material effect on
the entire concrete social phenomenon which is Capital with a capital “C”.
One such feature is the
“hoard” of money that is a necessary phenomenon within the cycle – the
indispensible slack or easement without which the machinery could not move.
In Volume 1, Marx takes
considerable pains to distinguish the miser (who hoards money) from the
capitalist (who puts money into circulation). There is no contradiction,
however, in Marx’s thinking. The hoard that arises in the cycle of capital is a
transitional, usable and re-chargeable reservoir, and not, like the miser’s
hoard of buried treasure, money that is permanently withheld from circulation
and use of any kind.
Where one must be careful is
with the unclear and conflicted representation of these matters that appears in
the vulgar economics of “analysts” in newspapers and in the mouths of pundits
and politicians today, where “capital” is invariably conceptualised in a
limited sense as a hoard. For example the sentence “I need capital to start my
business” always refers to a hoard, and only to a hoard.
In Marx, “accumulation”
refers to the assembly, and the constant reassembly at an ever-larger scale, of
all of the prerequisites for the extraction of surplus value, and not just to
the pump-priming hoard of money.
These prerequisites for
Capital also include the market, the proletariat, the bourgeoisie and the
bourgeois state with its bourgeois constitution and laws, the means of
communication, transport and trade, and the subordination of all other classes
to the rapacious needs of the bourgeois class.
In the case of an individual
business, the market for its goods or services is, in particular, a far more
critical prerequisite than the prior possession of a hoard of money.